Generally you have your engineers sign nondisclosure agreements as a condition of employment (I did).
No. Trade secrets are more important. Patents promote the spread of technology. Patents provide short term protection in exchange for disclosure. For example, a few years back, after our supplier for a particular antibiotic raised their price fourfold (they were the only supplier in the world for this antibiotic). A couple of engineers and I were charged with developing our own manufacturing process for this antibiotic. It turned out we had made it back in 1970 and we still had (frozen) a culture that made it. All we needed was an isolation and purification process. We had what we had done in 1970 and we had the patent literature. We found some pretty good processes in the patent literature, copied elements of them and developed a process that would cost us a third of what our supplier was charging. The supplier knew what we were doing and before we had even finished they had cut their price by two-thirds. We never implemented the new process because we got the lower price without having to do so. But until we had made a credible threat of going into business ourselves we could not get the low price. Copying other's (expired) patents made this possible. Had this knowledge existed as trade secrets, it would have been lost as none of the companies that had issued the patents were in the business anymore.All of these examples come from an industry where patents are a major part of the typical business model.
Our unit doesn't do patents, because that requires disclosure in an easily searchable format. We keep everything as trade secrets and disclose them to the public by making a poster presentation at an obscure meeting somewhere. We photograph the poster and the program listing the program as proof of disclosure. Now a competitor cannot independently develop our trade secret and patent it to prevent us from using it because you cannot patent publicly disclosed knowledge.
Exactly and that rise is described by the rise in per capital GDP AND by the rise in R, and by the rise of the real value of the stock index. The price of your stocks grow with the rising living standards. But you also get dividends, which represent excess return over and above the rise in the standard of living. As long as you reinvest some of the dividends your fortune will grow compared to the average fortune.Growth in the standard of living. If the economy gets a certain amount larger each year, so must your fortune, otherwise your share of the overall pie diminishes.
Of course they do. How can they not? Think carefully about it. The point of investing in enterprise is to make a better return than passive lending at the risk-free rate of return*. Since industrial times these rates have reflected the ability of nations to tax the rising future wealth of their nations to service the loans secured today. For government finance to be stable, real interest rates must not exceed long-term growth in national income because it is future income that is tapped to service the debt.You're arguing that capital markets in and of themselves cause concentrations of wealth.
Increased national income arises from both increased individual wealth (i.e. growth in R, asset prices, and GDP per capital) and population. As I have shown, individual wealth grows at about 2% rate since 1860. Population since WW II has grown at a about a 1% rate, which means the taxable national wealth has grown at about 3% rate. (Another way to say this is GDP growth has averaged about 3%)
Since 1945 II real T-bills have averaged 0.6%. Moody's Aaa corporates have shown average real rates of 2.7%. Ten year treasuries don't go back to 1945. Since 1953 they have generated about 2.5% in real return. These are all below the 3% level as they need to be over the very long run.
In theory, stock returns, assuming no change in valuation (P/R) over the long term will return 2% (due to long-term accumulation of R) plus average dividends. Since 1945 dividends have averaged 3.6%, giving a total theoretical return of 5.6%. Actual return has been 5.8%.
That is, stocks have returned about 3.3% more than investment in government debt, providing an additional return for enterprise as opposed to just passive lending at the benchmark rate This is the way it has to be, otherwise why start a business or invest in one if you could make just as much money lending out your savings? It has nothing to do with how the economy is structured. If capital markets exist, then this excess return over and above that obtained from passive lending must exist, or the capital markets themselves would not exist.
And that excess return is what creates concentrations of wealth.
Very little is invested in this way. The fraction of S&P500 shares traded on the exchanges that represent new issues is vanishingly small. The index I am using the the S&P500 and its precursor the Cowles index, which until the middle of the last century comprised all or just about all of the stocks on the NYSE and since then the largest 500 stocks traded on any US exchange.Wait, doesn't this assume that all of D is consumed? Isn't it likely that much of D becomes investment in new enterprises which would also contribute to the full value of R?
That is not to say that D is not reinvested back into R. Much of it is, but mostly by buying shares from other investors on the stock exchange. What these dividend investors are doing is buying more R to add to the R they already own.
No they haven't. Corporations continue to reinvest the same fraction of R (2%) as they always have. The fundamental return from capital (E) has fallen and so that means there is less D (as a fraction of R) available to pay out to investors. However, the return investors get is not E/R; it is E/P. Their return depends on what they paid for their R. Price determines return, not the company's prospects. Warren Buffet figured this out 60 years ago and that is part of the reason why he has been so successful.One of your charts shows that dividend returns for major stocks are now less than capital accumulation. This provides the data I lacked in my previous post and shows that major corporations have increasingly moved toward re-investment and thus capital growth has centralized in particular firms.
Back before 1920, when E/R was high at about 7%, P/R averaged around 1.0 and stock returns were about 7% in real terms. Since then E/R has run about 5% and P/R has run lower to--an average of 0.64 since 1920 So, though D/R has fallen from 5% to 3%, (i.e. the investment fundamentals have declined since 1920) D/P has only declined from 5% to 4.7%, a pretty small drop for such a big drop in the fundamentals.
No it's not. E/R runs at about 5%. Economic growth per person tracks R; it grows at 2%.The actual growth of the economy is closer to E.
Wrong. The standard of living rises with GDP per capita. Increases in GDP due to population growth are not reflected in living standards. GDP per capita tracks R not E. The value of the stock index (and hence the value of the idle rich's investments) rises in line with living standards. The dividend return is the extra they can live on, or re-invest if in excess. And reinvested dividends produce additional wealth concentration.In order to be part of the idle rich, and maintain one's fortune you need to achieve E plus money to live on. R simply measures the portion of the economy that is aggregating in the firms in whichever stock index you're using.
No they are not--see above.Average real stock returns are about 5% for the post-war period and average real interest rates look to be about the same.
************************************************** ************
*Historically, banking developed to make loans to governments, not to businesses. That is not to say they didn't make loans to private parties; they did, but the big business was finance of wars. And so there was a benchmark governmental interest rate (e.g. Venetian Prestiti, Genoese luoghi, British Consols, US Treasuries). The government loans from the biggest most stable nations with the longest record of successful payment formed these benchmark rates which economist term the risk-free rate of interest.