I averaged the Baa rates for the 1946-2003 period and got 7.7%. Subtracting the 4.1% inflation rate yield 3.6%, that same rate as the prime rate, and lower than the ROI of 4.4% over the same period.
No it isn't. First of all Baa is not at ROI, but lower. Investment funded by bonds will be a mixture of security having yield that fall between the Azz and Baa rate. That is why these two series are given.There are, of course, bonds of lower grade than Baa. I tried to find the quantities of new issues above and below the investment grade level, but was unable to do so. Since Baa is at ROI and there are definitely bonds below that grade, then an average interest near ROI is quite reasonable.
What you re thinking of are junk bonds, which have yield considered higher than Baa debt. Junk bonds are not used for capital investment, they are used for financial in much the same way as margin is used (except there is no collateral).
Reporting data for one month during a period of financial turmoil (e.g. an extremely rare negative inflation rate not seen in my lifetime) does not say much about interest rates relative to ROI over the long run.For loans, I went here, and see that all commercial and industrial loans for early May were at ~3%. Given the inflation rate of -1.3%, this would be roughly equal to ROI.
Um no. The interest rate return for the 1871-1920 was unaffected by the state, recall I got 4% just like they. But return to equity then was 7%, higher that the interest rate return. The authors did not give an equity return for that period so that can really say nothing about what happened then.This does seem like good evidence that -- in the actual economy -- equity returns exceed financing costs. As noted above, I do concede that this is possible. What's important to note here is that the conclusions above show quite plainly that the state plays a role in this situation.
During the 1945-2002 period I show equity returns that agree with what they have, but I show interest returns of 2.7% -- still lower than equity returns.
Now I will grant that the state was involved in creating what appear to be artificially low interest rate returns. After all the adjusted rate the paper's authors show is just about the same as the market rate in the 1871=1920 period suggesting that debt investors seek to conserve their returns.
This state intervention results in a lower cost of capital for businesses after 1920 than before. But my analysis shows that return to equity fell at the same time, removing any advantage gained by the artificially low interest rates. During the entire 130+ year period the return to equity remained stubbornly higher than the return to debt.
No it doesn't--see above.While the market for investment evens out the returns, the actual cost borne by businesses seems to diverge from this.
Why can't what the data shows without lots of handwaving be what the data shows? Why all the wembling? Methinks thou doth protest too much.I should note as well that the particular data sets used tend to skew us toward an analysis of the upper echelons of the economy. Partly, this is the data we have, but it seems likely that this difference is only an artifact of looking at the top of the economy and not the whole. Of course, for the situation to even out, that would mean that ROI is frequently lower than the cost of financing for smaller, less capitalized businesses. That is also a notable observation about the economy we have.
Um interest rates are interest rates. There are what they are.There are observations and there are "observations." Certainly this discussion demonstrates the difficulty in making a value-free analysis using economic statistics.
Hah! Obviously you don't do science or you wouldn't be so naive. Beaker experiments, as you call them, are hardly so easy to define. Right now at work we have an issue about the effect on filtration rates and yield in a chemical reaction step of removing a solvent. One faction (the scientists) sees higher yields and good filtration performance. The other faction (the engineers) sees lower yields and not very good filtration performance. I personally saw one of their filtrations and I swear to God it went flying through the filter. Didn't happen for us, and I'll be goddammed if I can tell you why. As an engineer I get to make the final decision on how to proceed, and I am letting the solvent change go. The other engineer (who is on vacation now) will be mad at me, but what can I d?, production wants to try the no solvent approach and since, as I see it, the risk of long filtration times and other hassles will be their problem and they want it, why not try it? After all, I did see this process work even if it doesn't in my lab. Maybe it will work in production.Economics is less of a hard science than, say, physics due to a trickier observation process. The temperature of the fluid in a beaker is much easier to define and determine in a value-free manner than the GDP of a country. The latter analysis requires determining what is and is not "production," what is and is not "domestic" and strains to find a measurement device that puts all the various items being measured into similar units. Economic analysis isn't just comparing a bunch of beaker measurements, it's more like comparing a bunch of beaker measuring experiments, each with different methodology, and trying to determine the overall beaker temperature trend. Good luck trying to do that without injecting some personal bias!
Well that's a good thing since empiricism is hardly pointless. Despite all the politics, scientists do eventually figure it out.All that is not to say that I take the extreme Austrian school position that empiricism is pointless.
Um observing bond prices at close is more precise than most scientific measurements, Most of the data I have been dealing with is a helluva lot more precise and accurate than filtration rates.Rather, when you say "I observe X" using economic data, we have to be extra careful to ensure we're factoring in possible errors in the process by which you arrived at that observation. This is because, often, economic "observations" are actually conclusions themselves.